Once upon a time in the land of Machinea there was a problem
The economy was powered by machines produced by different factories and rented
by producers. There were those machines that were distinguished by being a bit
wider than their substitutes, the W’s. There were those that were distinguished
by being a bit bigger than their substitutes, the B’s. And there was a third
kind that was atypical, the A’s. Each kind of machine was produced by a number
of factories. The largest number were the W’s, then the B’s then the A’s. The
machines were difficult to construct and thus there was significant variation
in their efficiency – by which is meant their productivity and reliability. Statistically
speaking it was known that an A was likely to be more efficient than a W or a B,
and a W more efficient than a B. As a result, since all they knew about the
machines was their type and average efficiency producers were reluctant to
hire them at the same rate as the W’s. And since it was frowned upon (and in
some place illegal) to pay a lower rent to a B than a W, the likelihood of a B
being rented was significantly less than the of a W being rented. The problem
that the policy makers wanted to solve was that the rate at which B’s were
hired, rented, was too low for their liking. The B factories were struggling to
survive.
The proffered solution was to strongly incentivize the
machine renters to hire more B’s, that is, to hire more than they would have
given their expectations of their efficiency. The reasoning underlying this
solution is that the low productivity of the B’s is endogenous, it is a result
their low rental earnings feeding back into the budgets of the B factories,
which, then, in turn, struggle to produce efficient machines. By intervening in
this way, a judicious public policy could break the vicious cycle producing self-sustaining
B inferiority. So, they instituted a policy of mandatory affirmative B rental
requirements. Each producer had to produce a report showing that his B-rentals
were at or above the proportion of B-machines in the market.
Though it seemed like a good idea, albeit at the cost of
some inefficiency imposed on the producers and their customers, there were
unintended consequences. The managers in the B factories realizing that the likelihood
of renting their machines was now higher, regardless of their efficiency, faced
a reduced incentive to produced efficient machines, and the quality of the
machines actually went down, even as they produced more machines. This raised
the hiring mandate under the policy and further reduced the incentive for
quality production. So, the policy was actually counter productive and
accentuated the negative cycle of B inferiority. The B factories now became
wholly dependent on the government to enforce the affirmative rental of their
machines.
A minority of policy makers and advisors pondered
alternative policies. Perhaps the initial problem lay in a structural defect in
many, though not all, of the B factories. These defects were endemic and though
not irremediable would require substantial changes in the incentives faced by
the B-producers. They suggested policies that would allow B’s to compete by
offering lower rental rates, and the scrapping of all policies that deterred
the B-producers from making painful but necessary changes.
There were other more wide-ranging policy change suggestions
like those that pertain to the inadequate training that B-producers received in
their training schools, but these are beyond the scope of this brief.
No comments:
Post a Comment